Skip to main content

State budget transfers to Health Insurance Funds for universal health coverage: institutional design patterns and challenges of covering those outside the formal sector in Eastern European high-income countries

An Erratum to this article was published on 07 March 2016

Abstract

Introduction

Many countries from the European region, which moved from a government financed and provided health system to social health insurance, would have had the risk of moving away from universal health coverage if they had followed a ā€œtraditionalā€ approach. The Eastern European high-income countries studied in this paper managed to avoid this potential pitfall by using state budget revenues to explicitly pay health insurance contributions on behalf of certain (vulnerable) population groups who have difficulties to pay these contributions themselves.

The institutional design aspects of their government revenue transfer arrangements are analysed, as well as their impact on universal health coverageĀ progress.

Methods

This regional study is based on literature review and review of databases for the performance assessment. The analytical framework focuses on the following institutional design features: rules on eligibility for contribution exemption, financing and pooling arrangements, and purchasing arrangements and benefit package design.

Results

More commonalities than differences can be identified across countries: a broad range of groups eligible for exemption from payment of health insurance contributions, full state contributions on behalf of the exempted groups, mostly mandatory participation, integrated pools for both the exempted and contributors, and relatively comprehensive benefit packages. In terms of performance, all countries have high total population coverage rates, but there are still challenges regarding financial protection and access to and utilization of health care services, especially for low income people.

Conclusion

Overall, government revenue transfer arrangements to exempt vulnerable groups from contributions are one option to progress towards universal health coverage.

Introduction

Several countries from Central and Eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union moved from a government financed and provided health system (Semashko model) to social health insurance (SHI) and introduced payroll taxes in the early 1990s (the full list of abbreviations can be found at the beginning of the document) [1]. Prior to this transition, they were characterized by high levels of financial protection and equity in access [2]. This reform would have had the risk of moving away from universal population coverage if implementation had followed a ā€œtraditionalā€ SHI approach that would focus on the formal sector employees and their dependents only. The countries covered in this paper mostly managed to avoid this potential pitfall as they transitioned to a contributory health insurance system [3]. In a ā€œtraditionalā€ SHI, those not contributing are not covered by the SHI (and thus only access state provided health services). But certain population groups are too poor to pay insurance contributions themselves and they need to be exempted from payment of health insurance contribution in order to remain entitled for health services. Thus, the government budget was the starting point for health financing, and state budget transfers were built into the design of the introduction of earmarked payroll taxes right from the start in nearly all countries. In fact, an increasing number of governments across the globe decide to use general government revenues, i.e. state budget transfers, to explicitly pay the contributions on behalf of non-contributing population groups, most often in addition to cross-subsidization from within the fundā€™s contribution, because they realised that progress towards universal health coverage (UHC) is not possible via payroll taxes of contributorsĀ only. This arrangement is also frequently captured and termed as government subsidization of insurance contributions, usually for economically inactive, vulnerable and poor population groups depending on the context [3ā€“7]. Vulnerable groups can be defined as ā€œgroups whose demographic, geographic, or economic characteristics impede or prevent their access to health care servicesā€ ([8], p. 253).

The specific focus on such budget transfer/subsidization arrangements via some form of health insurance, however, does not suggest that this financing arrangement is the only path to move towards or deepen UHC. One way is to expand user fee exemptions for specific groups, often also called free health-care policies for selected services and/or selected population groups, such as in Africa primarily. Other countries in Eastern and Central Europe and Central Asia have done so without payroll taxes, even though some of them established a separate purchasing agency, such as Latvia. These approaches tend not to be based on the affiliation and enrolment of entitled individuals. In the past, another group of countries tried to rely solely on payroll taxes and SHI to expand coverage without any state budget transfers. But a growing number of countries, both globally as well as in the European region, is applying a mix of contributory and non-contributory approach, by having chosen the path of government subsidization/government budget transfers to a health insurance type system. This deserves a specific analysis which is what this paper chose as its explicit focus.

The paperā€™s aim is to analyse the institutional design features of these government revenue transfer arrangements to SHI funds that serve to cover non-contributors in the health insurance systems, with a particular emphasis on those outside the formal sector, many of them being the poor and other vulnerable population groups, although it is difficult to separate these from other population groups that are also eligible for contribution exemption. For shortening purpose, from now on we refer to them as ā€œvulnerable groupsā€ or ā€œthe exemptedā€. The regional focus of this paper is on Eastern European high-income countries (as per World Bank country income classification [9]).

The existing body of literature contains single country studies, assessing SHI and government subsidization arrangements in particularly or discussing these as part of a broader health system review. Kutzin et al. [10] provide a comprehensive assessment of health financing reforms of former Eastern Bloc countries. Taking it from there, this paper explores in detail the specific institutional design features of SHI arrangements that incorporate government revenue transfer and assesses the progress and achievements or setbacks as to UHC. UHC means that ā€œall people have access to services and do not suffer financial hardship paying for themā€ ([7], p. 9). The performance assessment also includes a comparison between contributors and the exempt population groups. As a result, those critical institutional design features that are particularly conductive for UHC progress are identified. This analysis reveals that these financing arrangements are indeed one option to progress towards UHC.

The remaining of the paper is structured as follows. The next section outlines the applied methods and describes the analytical framework to research institutional design, as well as UHC related indicators to assess the performance of these financing arrangements. Section 3 presents findings, which is followed by a discussion of potential effects of specific institutional design aspects as well as of challenges on progress towards UHC in Section 4. The last section concludes with policy lessons.

Methods

This paperā€™s focus is on high-income Eastern European countries of the World Health Organization (WHO) European Region that introduced payroll taxation as a new earmarked tax for a new system of compulsory health insurance combined with government revenue transfers for non-contributors. These countries are Croatia, the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Poland, Slovakia and Slovenia, which were part of the former Eastern Bloc and which have turned into high-income countries over the past years, i.e. that were classified so for at least four consecutive years since 2008 [11]. This paper thus complements a paper by Mathauer et al. [12] of the same subject on low- and middle-income countries of the WHO European Region and is part of a series of regional studies and a global review all with the same research focus on state budget transfer/government subsidization arrangements.

To include or exclude countries in the study, in a first step, former Soviet and Eastern Bloc countries of the WHO European Region which have entered the group of high-income countries and for which the Global Health Expenditure Database indicated social security expenditure in 2012 were selected. In a second step, based on literature screening, countries were included if and when the SHI system was combined with government budget transfers for non-contributors. Once this list of countries was established, a detailed literature search was undertaken for each country in Science Direct, JSTOR, PubMed and Google. In Google, the first five pages, with ten results per page, were screened for publications and grey literature from universities, non-governmental organizations, governments, international organisations and alike. In the case of the other databases the first 100 findings were screened. In addition, the most recent Health Systems in Transition publications were used. For the institutional design analysis, the following search term combinations were used: health system OR health financing OR health insurance OR health vulnerable OR budget transfer OR government revenue transfer OR health subsid* AND the respective country AND/OR fundā€™s name.

The literature search for the performance assessment was based on the following search term combinations: health insurance coverage OR out-of-pocket payments (OOP) OR catastrophic health expenditure OR impoverish* health care OR financial protection OR access health OR utilization health care OR universal coverage AND the respective country AND/OR fundā€™s name. Furthermore, data was also collected from the WHO (for population size and OOP as a share of total health expenditure (THE)), Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development (OECD) (for the total population coverage rates) and Eurostat (for the share of unmet need) databases, as well as other country statistics.

The analytical framework used to assess institutional design of government subsidization arrangements is guided by the health financing functional approach of Kutzin [13] and looks specifically at the following aspects:

  1. 1.

    Revenue collection:

    • Eligibility rules for exemption from contributions and targeting;

    • Financing arrangements;

  2. 2.

    Pooling arrangements;

  3. 3.

    Purchasing arrangements and benefit package design.

The actual design features in place around these functions are the result of explicit or implicit policy choices.

Building upon the World Health Reportā€™s UHC conceptualization, progress towards UHC is assessed by looking at changes and improvement in the following three indicators: 1) Population coverage, understood as affiliation to the health financing arrangement under study here; 2) financial protection; and 3) access to and utilization of needed health care services [14]. TableĀ 1 outlines our framework and provides an overview of the institutional design aspects and related policy choices. It also shows how these potentially relate to and affect progress toward UHC. A detailed explanation of these institutional design aspects and indicators can be found in Additional file 1.

Table 1 Institutional design features of government revenue transfer/government subsidization

Results

Country and system overview

The analysis focuses on seven Eastern European countries, namely Croatia, the Czech Republic, Estonia, Hungary, Poland, Slovakia and Slovenia. TableĀ 2 provides a summary overview of countries. Prior to the system transition of the 1990s, these countries were classified as middle-income countries. During the Soviet Union era, their health systems was based on the Semashko model [15ā€“19] with heavy centralist planning and state owned and financed health facilities ensured high levels of financial protection and equity in access [2].

Table 2 Country overview

As part of the transition and health financing reforms, and with the aim to increase resource mobilization as a reaction to economic and state budget challenges, most countries introduced (and a few re-established) payroll taxation for a new system of compulsory SHI. Croatia, Czech Republic, Hungary, Slovakia and Slovenia coupled this with government revenue transfers in the early or mid-1990s, and Poland and Estonia did so in 1999 [20]. In a way, the shift to a SHI system made entitlement in principle contingent upon contributions, or payment of these by the state on behalf of those exempted. Yet, this link between contribution on behalf of the state and entitlement is often less explicit, like in Hungary or Czech Republic [21].

In a first step, entitlement to the health insurance coverage is based on permanent residence (Czech Republic, Estonia, Poland, Slovakia and Slovenia) or personal identification card (Hungary). As a second condition, definition of specific groups eligible for exemption from contributions are specified by law [16ā€“18, 22ā€“24].

Eligibility and targeting to identify the exempted

For the European region, it is important to specify the terminology of eligibility. Whereas in other regions, it is appropriate to talk of the ā€œsubsidizedā€, the European region requires some further terminological specification. As everybody was covered prior to the transition, the introduction of payroll taxes for formal sector employees and a contributory SHI system implied that various population groups needed to be exempted from contributions while still remaining entitled. The transfer of government revenues on behalf of and for the exempt has also led to the term of the ā€œstate insuredā€.

An overview of eligibility rules for those exempted from contributions in each country are provided in TableĀ 3, revealing strong commonalities as well as some distinct differences in a few countries. The population group most frequently exempted are the economically inactive people [22]. The exempted or state insured need to be distinguished from the insured family dependents who are covered via their principal affiliate through the principle of cross-subsidization by contributors. Family dependents usually include non-working spouses and children. Yet, in Croatia, Czech Republic, Hungary and Poland, children are actually part of the state insured for which the government provides explicit budget transfers.

Table 3 Eligible groups for exemption from contribution

While the categories of exempt persons are diverse, the most common population groups include the unemployed, pensioners, people receiving social assistance benefits, the poor and children below 18Ā years. Even though military personnel, who are employed by the Ministry of Defence, may be not considered as vulnerable, they are exempted from contributions in several countries (Croatia, Czech Republic, Estonia and Hungary). Estonia stands out to some extent: in addition to the groups for whom the government transfers revenues to the insurance fund, several population groups do not contribute and for which there is no state budget transfer made to contribute on their behalf. These encompass children up to 19Ā years, students, non-working pregnant women, non-working spouses of insured individuals, pensioners and disabled people entitled to special pensions. As in Croatia prior to its 2002 reform as in many Western European countries, this reflects the idea of insurance coverage of family dependents being cross-subsidized by the contributors.

TableĀ 4 provides an overview of the targeting and enrolment rules. Notably, most countries apply indirect targeting to identify eligible individuals for contribution exemption, based on socio-economic characteristics. Only Hungary and Poland use a direct targeting approach based on income means testing. The organization responsible for the identification of eligible population groups is most often the local government authority. Nonetheless, the identified eligible need to undertake active steps for their enrolment into the SHI in several countries.

Table 4 Targeting and enrolment rules

Financing arrangements

Two key health expenditure indicators related to the financing arrangements are general government health expenditure (GGHE) as a share of THE and expenditure of SHI funds as a share of GGHE (TableĀ 5).

Table 5 Financing arrangements and health expenditure indicators

GGHE as a share of THE is relatively high in 1995, but decreases in all countries, reaching the lowest level in Hungary at 64Ā % (from 84Ā % in 1995). The core purchaser of health services are the SHI agencies, as at least 80Ā % of GGHE is spent via them, and in three countries, this share is above 90Ā %. This share has mostly gone up, slightly though, in four of the seven countries, ranging from 83Ā % in Hungary to 94Ā % in Croatia. Importantly, this share includes the government revenue transfers. While precise data is only available for Hungary, Slovakia and Estonia, general government revenue transfer to the insurance funds do constitute an important share in all countries. In Hungary, the share of general government revenue as of total SHI funds is largest (above 50Ā %) [25], followed by Slovakia (34Ā % in 2011) [26]. It is important to note though that budget transfers are not necessarily linked only to finance the non-contributors, but may equally serve to provide funding to the whole pool of both contributors and non-contributors. In Hungary, for example, it is also a means to complement government taxation policy to reduce contribution rates for the contributors. Estonia is an exception again, as this share is approximately 5Ā % only (in 2012) [27], given that the non-contributors are largely cross-subsidized from contributors.

The institutional design features relating to the financing arrangements are presented in the first four columns of TableĀ 5. Importantly, in contrast to other regions, all countries studied here fully exempt those considered as unable to pay contributions, i.e. eligible for exemption, and they do not co-contribute at all. This aspect is crucial, because the collection of partial contributions from those outside formal sector employment may be cumbersome and potentially hinder vulnerable groups to get enrolled.

However, some groups outside the formal sector are not eligible for exemption, i.e. no specific state budget transfers are made on their behalf. These groups have to make contributions andĀ in some countries include the registered unemployed, farmers, craftsmen, pensioners and the self-employed.

TableĀ 5 also presents the logic or formula of determining the amount of the state budget transfer for non-contributors. In all countries but two, the government transfer for the exempted is based on a per capita amount that is formula-based. One exception is Hungary, where the government transfers a lump sum that is largely a result of budget negotiation processes [17]. This is also the case for all non-contributors of Croatia except those who receive unemployment benefits or pensions below the average net wage.

Various types of calculation formula and logics are found. First, in the Czech Republic and Slovakia, the transfer amount is determined by applying a set rate to the average wage, or as in Estonia, on an annually defined amount. Yet, notably, in Slovakia, the contribution rate for the contributing population is 14Ā % [22], whereas a rate of 4.78Ā % is applied for the exempt groups, pointing to cross-subsidization from contributors to the exempt. Secondly, in Poland, Croatia and Estonia, for social security beneficiaries, such as pensioners and the unemployed, the transfer amount is calculated by applying a set rate to social security pension or unemployment benefits, even though the source of funds are central government revenues, except in Estonia. A third way is applied in Slovenia where a fixed amount per capita is in place.

In all these countries, the transfer amount for the state insured has hence little to do with the average contribution amount of the contributors. Yet, this is not the objective. Different contribution rates applied to different ā€œcontributionā€ bases for different population groups within the same country are thus largely the result of taxation policy considerations as well as feasibility concerns. Importantly, these calculation formula are not intended to reflect an actuarial-based contribution to cover the exempted average expenditure. Instead, the aim is to achieve a funding level, in combination with contributions that cover the costs of care. Thus, in some countries, government budget transfers serve to ā€œsubsidizeā€ all insured, whether contributing or not.

Regarding the source of transfers, all countries make use of central government revenues. Only in Estonia are unemployment funds the source of funds transferred for the registered unemployed. Moreover, a few countries make use of hypothecated taxes: in Croatia, since 2008, car insurance tax and 32Ā % of revenues from excise taxes on tobacco are designated to health financing [28, 29]. Hungary also introduced earmarked taxes for health financing, such as the fat taxes levied on foods with high fat, sugar, salt and caffeine content [30].

Pooling arrangements

Strong commonalities in institutional design are found with respect to pooling arrangements (TableĀ 6). As the countries transitioned and shifted from a universalist Semashko system (covering all population groups) to a compulsory SHI system, the most crucial feature is that all countries built in universality and chose to establish an integrated fund for both the contributors and non-contributors with the aspiration and logic to again cover the total population. While this followed the pre-transition logic of coverage for all, setting up an integrated pool for all population groups is not self-evident, as evidence from other regions reveals.

Table 6 Pooling arrangements

This came along with another important policy choice, namely to introduce mandatory coverage for all - both contributors as well as non-contributors - except in Estonia and Poland, where a few smaller population groups can obtain insurance coverage on a voluntary basis.

Even though contributors and exempt are within the same pool, there is fragmentation in some countries. While Croatia, Estonia, Hungary, Poland and Slovenia have a single national pool, the Czech Republic and Slovakia introduced a multiple payer system at a later stage, with 9 funds [31] and 3 funds [22] respectively, combined with a risk equalization mechanism. In the Czech Republic, each health insurance fund collects the SHI contributions from all its members, or receives state budget transfers for the state insured. Individuals are free to enrol in any health insurance fund and they have the right to choose it once a year [24]. In 1994, the government introduced a risk adjustment mechanism to equalize available funds across insurers. The revenues subject to the risk adjustment mechanism comprised 100Ā % of state transfers on behalf of the state insured and 60Ā % of revenues from contributors. These funds were redistributed among insurers taking into account the number of state insured persons, further adjusted by two age categories (below and above 60Ā years). Those above 60Ā years of age are given a triple weight in the risk adjustment formula [32]. Although this approach allowed for more financial sustainability, it was ineffective because it did not eliminate incentives for risk selection [32]. Thus, in the late 2000s, the risk adjustment mechanisms was further modified, with 100Ā % of revenues from contributions being subject to redistribution and with a risk adjustment formula now based on age and gender, and no longer on exemption status. This further reduced incentives for risk selection [24].

In Slovakia, soon after the introduction of its SHI, competition between non-profit insurers was introduced [32]. Since 2010, after merging and various reforms in the legal status of the funds, the system ended up having three health insurance funds. Each collects SHI contributions and receives government revenue transfers, and individuals are free to enrol in any of them. A risk adjustment mechanism has been set up, initially based on an age- and gender-related risk index, which, since 2010, is applied in a differential way for the state insured and the contributors. The different risk-adjusted allocations for different population groups result in certain groups of the state insured being more attractive (e.g., students) than others (e.g., unemployed), possibly increasing incentives for risk selection by insurers [22].

Purchasing arrangements and benefit package design

Since all countries operate integrated schemes for both contributors and the exempt, provider payment mechanisms and rates applied are the same for both groups, thus giving providers no immediate incentive for cream-skimming patients.

As TableĀ 7 shows, in all the countries covered here, the SHI benefit package is relatively comprehensive and covered health services are the same for both the non-contributors and contributors. Where covered services offered at private health care providers are included, access for the state insured is the same as for contributors.

Table 7 Benefit package

Although the range of covered health care benefits is broad in all countries, cost-sharing mechanisms are in place, with an overview provided in TableĀ 8. However, most countries provide cost-sharing exemptions for some but not all state insured groups and non-contributors as well as some groups among the contributors.

Table 8 Cost-sharing arrangements

Assessment of UHC related performance indicators

Population coverage

This section seeks to explore how countries fared on their path to universal health since they shifted to the hybrid financing system of SHI and state budget transfers. It starts by looking at total population enrolment rates. The population enrolled in SHI as a share of the whole population is above 99Ā % in 2 out of the 7 analysed countries (Czech Republic and Slovenia). For the other countries their population coverage rate is equally very high and above 90Ā % (see TableĀ 9).

Table 9 Population coverage rates

Data on the share of the exempt or state insured as of the total population is not available for all countries. Estimations suggest that the largest share is found in Croatia (64Ā %), followed by Slovakia (approx. 62Ā %) and the Czech Republic (58Ā %) [19]. Estonia has the lowest share of 4.9Ā %, but this needs to be seen in addition to the 45.8Ā % of the non-contributing population being cross-subsidized by contributors. These figures indicate the significance of exemption and non-contribution and the importance of government revenue transfers.

An important question is which type of people are not covered in the countries with a population coverage rate below 100Ā % and whether they fall outside the eligible groups for exemption or non-contribution. In fact, people of Roma ethnic groups may be most likely to remain uninsured. In 2011, 7Ā % of the Roma population in the Czech Republic was not covered by the SHI [33], 9Ā % in Hungary [34], and 3Ā % in Slovakia respectively [35]. However, these numbers are small in absolute terms considering that the Roma population represents approximately 3Ā % of the total population in the Czech Republic [33] and 2Ā % in Hungary and Slovakia [26].

In Estonia, the long-term unemployed and men that do not belong to the economically active population between 30 and 50Ā years old are not part of the defined eligible groups for non-contributions and are thus more likely not to be insured [36]. In the richest income quintile every tenth person was found to not have insurance, whereas the probability of being uninsured is four times higher among people in the lowest income quintile [16]. In Poland, approximately 1-2Ā % of the population, namely the very poor, are uninsured. However, since 2004, regardless of insurance status, very poor people as well as uninsured pregnant women and children below 18Ā years have access, though limited, to free publicly-financed health services [37].

Finally, a very small percentage of the population is not covered, because these individuals are insured in other EU Member States (e.g. in Slovakia, this is 2.4Ā % of population [22]).

Financial protection

Financial protection data that differentiates between contributors and non-contributors is not available. Therefore, this and the following sub-section also assess data differentiated along income quintiles, although non-contributors cannot be simply equated with low income quintile population groups. Nonetheless, looking at income quintile differences helps revealing inequities across the whole population.

TableĀ 10 summarizes data on OOP expenditure. The OOP health expenditures as share of THE vary across the analysed countries, ranging from 12Ā % in Slovenia to 28Ā % in Hungary, which is very low in global comparison. Only in Poland did this share decrease, and in Croatia and Estonia only very marginally, since the introduction of the SHI system including its government revenue transfers. Data regarding the share of OPPs as household expenditure by income quintile or decile is only available for a few countries. In the Czech Republic, OOPs are low and distributed relatively even across household income deciles, in contrast to Estonia, Hungary and Slovakia, where financial protection of low income quintiles is a real concern.

Table 10 OOP expenditure

Data to reveal changes and disaggregation in the incidence of catastrophic and impoverishing expenditure is scarce (TableĀ 11). In Hungary, both indicators show a slight improvement, so does the incidence for impoverishing expenditure in Poland. In contrast, in the Czech Republic, incidence of catastrophic expenditure increased slightly, whereas in Estonia, it is fluctuating with no clear trend, while its incidence of impoverishing expenditure for the two bottom income quintiles seems to go down over the recent years.

Table 11 Incidence of catastrophic and impoverishing expenditure

Access to and utilization of health care services

TableĀ 12 provides data on utilization rates of health services across countries. Utilization rates of general practitioners (GP) services are equitable along income quintiles in 3 out of 7 countries (Czech Republic, Hungary and Slovenia). With respect to dental care, utilization rates are equitable in the Czech Republic and Slovenia, while in Croatia, Estonia, Hungary and Poland there is some inequity, with high-income people being advantaged.

Table 12 Utilization rates and unmet needs

In 2012, in all countries, except Slovenia where data is not available, within the poorest income quintile, the percentage of people reporting unmet needs for medical examination is higher in comparison to better-off people. Among the reasons, unaffordability (too expensive), too long distance to travel or long waiting lists are mentioned [38].

In the Czech Republic and Hungary, when it comes to utilization rates and access to health services of specific population groups, the Roma are disadvantaged compared to non-Roma (see last column of TableĀ 12). Moreover, in Poland, the poorest uninsured people receive mostly inpatient care and they have limited access to primary care or dental services in practice [37].

Discussion

This section examines the plausible effects of the institutional design features on performance, i.e. progress towards UHC.

Effects of eligibility and targeting

Overall, all countries have both a very high total population enrolment rate as well as a high share of the exempt and non-contributors. These countries achieve practically universality in population coverage. This is despite the fact that there are large shares of the population outside formal sector employment, which in the logic of a ā€œtraditionalā€ compulsory SHI would be the principle entry point for coverage. Yet, eligibility of the exempt is defined both broadly as well as specifically to capture those outside formal sector employment. High population coverage rates are effectively achieved by primarily applying an indirect targeting approach. Most important seems the inclusion of the (unregistered) unemployed, which captures a large part of those outside formal sector employment. However this is not the case in Poland, Slovenia and Estonia for the long-term employed. On the other hand, these countries have not chosen to "automatically" enrol all those outside the formal sector, possibly to avoid informality becoming attractive. As a result, population coverage is not 100Ā % in that some few population groups and individuals remain uncovered. In sum, the specific definition of eligible groups for exemption is decisive for the level of population coverage. Interestingly, in most countries (Croatia, Czech Republic, Hungary, Poland, Slovakia), children are part of the state insured and their coverage is financed through government budget transfers, even though family insurance is in place in all the 7 countries studied here. This reduces in principle the degree of cross-subsidization among contributors. It also further blurs the line between coverage of family dependents and otherwise vulnerable population groups financed through government budget transfers.

Yet, there are gaps in health insurance coverage of certain groups, and thus countries are undertaking efforts to reach these unreached groups. In Estonia, for example, since the end of 2002, individuals who might otherwise remain uninsured can acquire voluntary coverage when meeting the following eligibility criteria: Estonian residents who receive a pension fund from another country and individuals who are not currently eligible, but who have been members of the Estonian Health Insurance Fund for at least 12Ā months in the two years prior to applying for voluntary membership, as well as their dependents (students and people temporarily out of work but not registered as unemployed) [16].

In Poland, although people with low income are eligible for exemption, there are still uninsured poor individuals [37]. A reason for this might be the income threshold set by the authorities to establish the eligibility of individuals to be exempt. Despite being eligible, some groups such as the children of uninsured parents and homeless were not eligible for mandatory membership and did not have the capacity to pay contributions to join the system voluntarily before 2007. Therefore, decision makers tried to identify those population groups of excluded people in order to provide access to care and coverage to them.

Effects of financing and pooling arrangements

The analysed health systems are strongly based on solidarity. Importantly, all countries have avoided fragmentation and allow for risk pooling by having established an integrated fund for both the exempted and the contributors. Moreover, the levels of state budget transfers are substantial in all countries, and found to be relatively high in Hungary and Slovakia for which data is available. State budget transfers are calculated on the basis of minimum wage, average wage or unemployment benefits or another defined amount, unless they represent a fixed amount of the budget. In general, unemployment benefits or the minimum wage are much smaller than the average wage, and thus using the average wage as assessment base leads to higher per capita budget transfers and potentially lower internal cross-subsidization. This also determines the level of equity in financing as well as the fundā€™s financial sustainability.

For example, in Slovakia, state budget transfers amounted to about one third of total revenues of the SHI system, while about two thirds of the population are exempted (data for 2009, [22]). The Slovak SHI system is thus strongly based on cross-subsidization of contributors. Likewise in Estonia, there is a very high level of cross-subsidization within the pool where almost half of the insured population contribute, whereas state budget transfers are made for around 5Ā % of the population, whilst the rest of the insured is cross-subsidized from within the pool, with everybody being entitled to the same benefit package [39]. Thus, in the long run, the systemā€™s financial fairness and sustainability might be threatened since the revenues largely come from contributions of the working population. In addition, the population is ageing and the share of working age individuals is decreasing [16]. Despite the recommendations by the Estonian Health Insurance Fund and WHOā€™s specialists in 2009 to extend the public revenue base, i.e. apply the social tax to non-wage income and to introduce government budget transfers on behalf of pensioners [40], the Estonian Government did not choose to implement this reform option [41].

Effects of benefit package design

The benefit package design and, equally important, the cost-sharing mechanisms determine the degree of financial protection and utilization of health care services. In fact, in most countries (Croatia, Estonia, Hungary, Poland and Slovakia), there is inequity in access for lower income quintiles. In all of these countries, this is a result of unaffordable co-payments, especially for prescribed drugs, with the low income people being the most affected [18, 22, 36, 42ā€“44].

After the transition and the shift to the new financing arrangement, combining SHI contributions and state budget transfers, OOPs increased in the Czech Republic, Hungary, Slovakia and Slovenia (TableĀ 10) as a result of high utilization or overutilization of health care services [16, 17, 22, 24]. Hungary and Slovakia tried to manage utilization by introducing cost-sharing mechanisms [17, 22], but they were not successful in reducing over-utilization. In contrast Slovenia increased co-payments with only a small impact on access to health care and financial protection [21, 23], moreover since a policy on voluntary health insurance helped to cover user charges [45].

In Poland, uninsured poor individuals have free access to publicly financed services, yet this does not solve the challenge that poor people have no means to buy drugs for example, and thus, even if not always necessary, they prefer hospitalization care, where drugs are included.

Conclusions

This paper explored the trends and patterns of institutional design aspects of the existing financing arrangements, that is the mix of compulsory SHI contributions and state budget transfers with a focus on population groups outside formal sector employment and especially vulnerable population groups. Notably, the analysis revealed more commonalities than differences across countries. First of all, in all countries, vulnerable groups are fully exempted from paying contributions. The main challenge here is to ensure that the amount of transfers in combination with payroll contributions as a function of taxation policy are sufficient and allow for sustainability of the health insurance system in the long run.

Second, all countries avoided fragmentation by having established integrated pools for both the exempted and contributors. This allowed for risk pooling and strong redistributive capacity. Additionally, coverage is mandatory for both the exempted and the contributors with no opt out option of the system, with the exception of a few contributing groups in Estonia and Poland.

Third, the benefit packages are relatively comprehensive and, more importantly, all insured individuals, exempted as well as contributing, are entitled to the same benefit package. In most countries, this is combined with exemptions from cost-sharing for several, though not all, exempted groups. Concerns, though, remain for some of the vulnerable groups specifically that are not exempted from cost-sharing, and options need to be found such that they do not face difficulties in access to and utilization of health care services.

In terms of progress towards UHC, all countries have a very high total population enrolment rate (above 90Ā %). Yet, there are still groups not eligible for exemption and immediate measures within the same exemption logic should be taken in this regard. There are also challenges with respect to financial protection, because in half of the countries (Croatia, Estonia, Hungary, Slovakia), lower income quintiles face a heavy burden of OOPs.

Further research should be conducted to analyse the impact of these arrangements with respect to UHC progress on the basis of which to explore options how to improve coverage, especially for vulnerable groups. Governments should take further steps in better defining, identifying and exempting the potential vulnerable groups (e.g. the very poor, unregistered unemployed). Another question is how they can address the issue of system sustainability. Moreover, differentiated data for the exempt versus contributors, insured versus uninsured, and across income quintiles is needed. Providing answers to all these questions may help countries to deepen their achievements in UHC.

Overall, this analysis suggests that the government revenue transfer arrangements for selected and in particular vulnerable groups who are exempt from contributions, have been an effective way to set up a social health insurance that avoided coverage gaps for those outside the formal sector. This mixed financing system has thus made it possible to largely maintain their population coverage level after the system transition. Together with country experiences from other regions, it confirms that this approach of exempting vulnerable groups from contributions, or as termed elsewhere their subsidization, is one option to progress towards universal health coverage, contingent upon conducive institutional design.

Abbreviations

GDP:

gross domestic product

GGHE:

general government health expenditure

GP:

general practitioners

OECD:

Organization for Economic Co-operation and Development

OOP:

out-of-pocket payments

SHI:

social health insurance

THE:

total health expenditure

UHC:

universal health coverage

WHO:

World Health Organization

References

  1. Mossialos E, Dixon A. Funding health care: an introduction. In: Mossialos E, Dixon A, Figueras J, Kutzin J, editors. Funding health care: options for Europe. Buckingham, Philadelphia: Open University Press; 2002. p. 1ā€“30.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  2. Preker A, Jakab M, Schneider M. Health financing reforms in central and eastern Europe and the former Soviet Union. In: Mossialos E, Dixon A, Figueras J, Kutzin J, editors. Funding health care: options for Europe. Buckingham, Philadelphia: Open University Press; 2002. p. 80ā€“108.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  3. Davis C. Understanding the legacy: health financing systems in the USSR and central and eastern Europe prior to transition. In: Kutzin J, Cashin C, Jakab M, editors. Implementing health financing reform Lessons from countries in transition: WHO on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies; 2010. p. 25ā€“63.

  4. Meng Q, Yuan B, Jia L, Wang J, Yu B, Gao J et al. Expanding health insurance coverage in vulnerable groups: a systematic review of options. Health Policy and Planning. 2010:1ā€“12. doi:10.1093/heapol/czq038

  5. Acharya A, Vellakkal S, Taylor F, Masser E, Satija A, Burke M, et al. Impact of national health insurance for the poor and the informal sector in low- and middle-income countries: systematic review. London: EPPI-Centre, Social Science Research Unit, Institute of Education, University of London; 2012.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  6. Bitran R. Universal health coverage and the challenge of informal employment. Lessons from developing countries. HNP discussion paper. Washington: World Bank; 2014.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  7. WHO. The World Health Report: Health Systems Financing: The path to universal coverage. Geneva: World Health Organization; 2010.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  8. Blumenthal D, Mort E, Edwards J. The efficacy of primary care for vulnerable population groups. Health Services Research. 1995;30((1 Pt 2)):253ā€“73.

    CASĀ  PubMedĀ  PubMed CentralĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  9. World Bank. World Bank country classification [Available from: http://data.worldbank.org/about/country-classifications.

  10. Kutzin J, Cashin C, Jakab M. Implementing health financing reform. Lessons from countries in transition. Copenhagen: WHO on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies; 2010.

  11. World Bank. Country and lending group 2014 [Available from: http://data.worldbank.org/about/country-and-lending-groups#High_income.

  12. Mathauer I, Theisling M, Vilcu I, Mathivet B. Government budget transfers to health insurance arrangements to cover vulnerable and otherwise uninsured population groups: Institutional design patterns and challenges in low- and middle- income countries of the WHO European Region. Geneva, Switzerland : WHO, Department of Health Systems Governance and Financing; 2015.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  13. Kutzin J. A descriptive framework for country-level analysis of health care financing arrangements. Health Policy. 2001;56:171ā€“204.

    ArticleĀ  CASĀ  PubMedĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  14. Kutzin J. Health financing for universal coverage and health system performance: concepts and implications for policy. Bulletin WHO. 2013;91(8):602ā€“11.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  15. Kinkorova J, Topolcan O. Overview of healthcare system in the Czech Republic. The EPMA Journal. 2012;3(1):4.

    ArticleĀ  PubMedĀ  PubMed CentralĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  16. Koppel A, Kahur K, Habicht T, Saar P, Habicht J, van Ginneken E. Estonia: Health system review. Health Systems in Transition. 2008;10:1ā€“230.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  17. Gaal P, Szigeti S, Csere M, Gaskins M, Panteli D. Hungary: Health system review. Health Systems in Transition. 2011;13:1ā€“266.

    PubMedĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  18. Sagan A, Panteli D, Borkowski W, Dmowski M, Domanski F, Czyzewski M, et al. Poland: Health system review. Health Systems in Transition. 2011;13:1ā€“193.

    PubMedĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  19. Nemec J, Cankar SS, Kostadinova D, Maly I, Darmopilova Z. How to finance health services: CEE experience with switch from "Semashko model" to health insurance systems. Paper prepared for the ICPP Panel 67. Grenoble: Comparative health reforms in Central and Eastern Europe: Europeanization versus subsidiarity.

  20. Sheiman I, Langenbrunner J, Kehler J, Cashin C, Kutzin J. Sources of funds and revenue collection: reforms and challenges. In: Kutzin J, Cashin C, Jakab M, editors. Implementing health financing reform Lessons from countries in transition. Copenhagen: WHO on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies; 2010. 85ā€“118.

  21. Gotsadze G, Gaal P. Coverage decisions: benefit entitlements and patient cost sharing. In: Kutzin J, Cashin C, Jakab M, editors. Implementing health financing reform Lessons from countries in transition. Copenhagen: WHO on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies; 2010. 187ā€“217.

  22. Szalay T, Pazitny P, Szalayova A, Frisova S, Morvay K, Petrovic M, et al. Slovakia: Health system review. Health Systems in Transition. 2011;13:1ā€“200.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  23. Albreht T, Turk E, Toth M, Ceglar J, Marn S, Pribakovic Brinovec R, et al. Slovenia: Health system review. Health Systems in Transition. 2009;11:1ā€“168.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  24. Bryndova L, Pavlokova K, Roubal T, Rokosova M, Gaskins M, van Ginneken E. Czech Republic: Health system review. Health Systems in Transition. 2009;11:1ā€“122.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  25. Kutzin J. Health financing for Universal Health Coverage. Addis Ababa, Ethiopia: European Union Regional Health and Education Seminar; 2013.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  26. Statistical Office of the Slovak Republic. Statistical Yearbook of the Slovak Republic. 2012.

  27. Estonian Health Insurance Fund. Annual report. 2012.

  28. Voncina L, Strizrep T, Bagat M, Pezelj-Duliba D, Pavic N, Polasek O. Croatian 2008ā€“2010 health insurance reform: hard choices toward financial sustainability and efficiency. Croat Med J. 2012;53(1):66ā€“76.

    ArticleĀ  PubMedĀ  PubMed CentralĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  29. Svaljek S. The recent health reform in Croatia: True reforms or just a fundraising exercise? Health Policy. 2014;115((1)):36ā€“43.

    ArticleĀ  PubMedĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  30. Jowett M. Revenue collection. Tunis, Tunisia: WHO Advanced Course on Health Financing for Universal Health Coverage; 2014.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  31. Centre for International Reimbursements. Health care in the Czech Republic 2013 [Available from: http://www.cmu.cz/en/links-info-en/health-insurance-system-in-cz.

  32. Kutzin J, Shishkin S, Bryndova L, Schneider P, Hrobon P. Reforms in the pooling of funds. In: Kutzin J, Cashin C, Jakab M, editors. Implementing health financing reform Lessons from countries in transition. Copenhagen: WHO on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies; 2010. p. 119ā€“53.

  33. European Roma Rights Centre. Czech Republic: Country profile 2011ā€“2012.

  34. Dotcho M. The health situation of Roma communities: Analysis of the data from the UNDP/World Bank/EC Regional Roma Survey 2011. Bratislava: Roma Inclusion Working Papers; 2012.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  35. Kuhlbrandt C, Footman K, Rechel B, McKee M. An examination of Roma health insurance status in Central and Eastern Europe. European Journal of Public Health. 2014;24(5):707ā€“12.

    ArticleĀ  PubMedĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  36. Vork A, Habicht J, Xu K, Kutzin J. Income-related inequality in health care financing and utilization in Estonia since 2000. Copenhagen: WHO Regional Office for Europe; 2010.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  37. Marek M. Poland: Poverty and health. Poverty and social exclusion in the WHO European Region: health systems respond. Copenhagen: WHO Regional Office for Europe; 2010. p. 124ā€“35.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  38. Eurostat. SILC database 2013 [Available from: http://ec.europa.eu/eurostat/web/health/health-care/data/database.

  39. Habicht T, Habicht J. Estonia: "Good practice" in expanding health care coverage. In: Gottret P, Schieber GJ, Waters HR, editors. Good practices in health financing Lessons from reforms in low- and middle-income countries. Washington: The World Bank; 2008. p. 227ā€“67.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  40. Thomson S, Vork A, Habicht T, Roovali L, Evetovits T, Habicht J. Responding to the challenge of finanacial sustainability in Estonia's health system. Copenhagen: WHO Regional Office for Europe; 2010.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  41. Thomson S, Habicht T, Roovali L, Evetovits T, Habicht H. Responding to the challenge of financial sustainability in Estonia's health system: one year on. Copenhagen: WHO Regional Office for Europe; 2011.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  42. Vork A, Saluse J, Habicht J. Income-related inequality in health care financing and utilization in Estonia 2000ā€“2007. Copenhagen: WHO Regional Office for Europe; 2009.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  43. Baji P, Pavlova M, Gulacsi L, Groot W. Changes in equity in out-of-pocket payments during the period of health care reforms: Evidence from Hungary. International Journal for Equity in Health. 2012;11:36.

    ArticleĀ  PubMedĀ  PubMed CentralĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  44. Pristas I, Bilic M, Pristas I, Voncina L, Krcmar N, Polasek O, et al. Health care needs, utilization and barriers in Croatia - Regional and Urbanā€“rural differences. Coll Antropol. 2009;33:121ā€“30.

    PubMedĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  45. Thomson S. What role for voluntary health insurance? In: Kutzin J, Cashin C, Jakab M, editors. Implementing health financing reform Lessons from countries in transition. Copenhagen: WHO on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies; 2010. p. 299ā€“325.

  46. Xu K. Distribution of health payments and catastrophic expenditures. Methodology. Discussion paper 2. Geneva: WHO; 2005.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  47. Probst L, Mathauer I, Vilcu I. Government subsidization of health insurance type arrangements for vulnerable and informally employed population groups in Asian low- and middle-income countries: Institutional design patterns and implementation issues. Geneva, Switzerland: WHO, Department of Health Systems Governance and Financing; 2015.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  48. WHO. Global Health Expenditure Database 2014 [Available from: http://apps.who.int/nha/database.

  49. World Bank. World Data Bank 2014 [Available from: http://data.worldbank.org/.

  50. Voncina L, Jemiai N, Merkur S, Golna C, Maeda A, Chao S, et al. Croatia: Health system review. Health Systems in Transition. 2006;8(7):1ā€“108.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  51. Saltman RB. Social health insurance in perspective: the challenge of sustaining stability. In: Saltman RB, Busse R, Figueras J, editors. Social health insurance systems in western Europe. Berkshire, England: Open University Press; 2004. p. 3ā€“20.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  52. Gaal P. Health care systems in transition: Hungary. Copenhagen: WHO Regional Office for Europe on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies; 2004.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  53. Boulhol H, Sowa A, Golinowska S, Sicari P. Improving the health-care system in Poland. Economics Department working paper no. 957. OECD, 2012.

  54. Hlavacka S, Wagner R, Riesberg A. Health care systems in transition: Slovakia. Copenhagen: WHO Regional Office for Europe on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies; 2004.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  55. Health Insurance Institute of Slovenia. Compulsory health insurance 2009 [Available from: http://www.zzzs.si/zzzs/internet/zzzseng.nsf/o/DB29291A87496668C1256E8900489918.

  56. Voncina L, Dzakula A, Mastilica M. Health care funding reforms in Croatia: A case of mistaken priorities. Health Policy. 2007;80:144ā€“57.

    ArticleĀ  PubMedĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  57. Couffinhal A, Habicht T. Health system financing in Estonia: situation and challanges in 2005. 2005. WHO Regional Office for Europe.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  58. Croatian Bureau of Statistics. Statistical Yearbook of the Republic of Croatia. 2011.

  59. OECD. OECD Health Data: Social Protection 2015 [Available from: http://0-www-oecd--ilibrary-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/social-issues-migration-health/data/oecd-health-statistics/oecd-health-data-social-protection_data-00544-en.

  60. Rokosova M, Hava P, Schreyogg J, Busse R. Health care systems in transition: Czech Republic. WHO Regional Office for Europe on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies. 2005.

  61. Scheil-Adlung X, Kuhl C. Social security for all: Addressing inequities in access to health care for vulnerable groups in countries of Europe and Central Asia. Geneva: International Labour Organization, Social Security Department; 2011.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  62. Xu K, Evans DB, Kawabata K, Zeramdini R, Klavus J, Murray C. Household catastrophic health expenditure: a multicountry analysis. The Lancet. 2003;362:111ā€“17.

    ArticleĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  63. Krutilova V. Cost sharing of patients for health care - forms, extent, impacts. Brno: Masaryk University; 2013.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  64. Vork A, Saluse J, Reinap M, Habich T. Out-of-pocket payments and health care utilization in Estonia, 2000ā€“2012. WHO Regional Office for Europe: Copenhagen; 2014.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  65. Luczak J, Garcia-Gomez P. Financial burden of drug expenditures in Poland. Health Policy. 2012;105:256ā€“64.

    ArticleĀ  PubMedĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  66. Saksena P, Xu K, Durairaj V. The drivers of catastrophic expenditure: outpatient services, hospitalization or medicines? World Health Report 2010, Background Paper, 21. Geneva: WHO; 2010.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  67. Devaux M, de Looper M. Income-related inequalities in health service utilisation in 19 OECD countries, 2008ā€“2009, OECD Health Working Papers, No. 58. Paris: OECD Publishing; 2012.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  68. Wang H, Switlick K, Ortiz C, Zurita B, Connor C. Health insurance handbook. How to make it work. Washington: World Bank; 2012.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  69. Gwatkin DR. Are free government health services the best way to reach to poor? HNP discussion paper. Washington: World Bank; 2004.

    Google ScholarĀ 

  70. Coady D, Grosh M, Hoddinott J. Targeting of transfers in developing countries: Review of lessons and experience. Washington: World Bank; 2004.

    BookĀ  Google ScholarĀ 

  71. Kutzin J. Conceptual framework for analyzing health financing systems and the effects of reforms. In: Kutzin J, Cashin C, Jakab M, editors. Implementing health financing reform Lessons from countries in transition. Copenhagen: WHO on behalf of the European Observatory on Health Systems and Policies; 2010. p. 3ā€“24.

  72. Normand C, Weber A, Carrin G, Doetinchem O, Mathauer I, Scheil-Adlung X et al. Social health insurance. A guidebook for planning. Asian Development Bank, International Labour Organization, World Health Organization, German Technical Cooperation 2009.

  73. Witter S. Health financing in developing and transitional countries. Briefing paper for OXFAM. York: University of York; 2002.

    Google ScholarĀ 

Download references

Acknowledgements

We gratefully acknowledge very valuable comments from Tamas Evetovis, Sarah Thomson and Benoit Mathivet. We also greatly benefited from discussions with Joe Kutzin and Matthew Jowett. The authors are responsible for all remaining errors. Finally, financial support to Ileana Vilcu's consultant contract from the EU-WHO Universal Health Coverage Partnership Programme is gratefully acknowledged.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Inke Mathauer.

Additional information

Competing interests

The authors declare that they have no competing interests.

Authorsā€™ contribution

IM conceived the study and its design with contributions from IV. IV undertook most of the literature review. Both authors undertook the analysis and interpretation of data and drafted the manuscript. Both authors have read and approved the final manuscript.

Authorsā€™ information

IM is a health systems development and health financing specialist in the Department of Health Systems Governance and Financing at the World Health Organization in Geneva. At the start of this research, IV was a master student at the University of Lausanne and then worked as a consultant within the same department at WHO.

Additional file

Additional file 1:

Analytical Framework. Provides a detailed explanation of TableĀ 1 based on which the analytical framework was developed [13, 14, 20, 21, 46, 68ā€“73]. (PDF 35 kb)

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution 4.0 International License (http://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/4.0/), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided you give appropriate credit to the original author(s) and the source, provide a link to the Creative Commons license, and indicate if changes were made. The Creative Commons Public Domain Dedication waiver (http://creativecommons.org/publicdomain/zero/1.0/) applies to the data made available in this article, unless otherwise stated.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Check for updates. Verify currency and authenticity via CrossMark

Cite this article

Vilcu, I., Mathauer, I. State budget transfers to Health Insurance Funds for universal health coverage: institutional design patterns and challenges of covering those outside the formal sector in Eastern European high-income countries. Int J Equity Health 15, 7 (2016). https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.1186/s12939-016-0295-y

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://0-doi-org.brum.beds.ac.uk/10.1186/s12939-016-0295-y

Keywords